Menu Close

Slashing support: How the NDIS is leaving the most vulnerable behind

James Rosier

Credit: Source (screenshot via YouTube)

As funding cuts take hold, the NDIS is drifting further from its founding promise, leaving those with the greatest needs at the greatest risk.

Trouble is brewing in the National Disability Insurance Scheme (NDIS). You may have heard little of the impending funding changes. With the high-profile Minister Bill Shorten retiring before the Federal Election, NDIS discussion was largely absent from the election debate.

Seemingly overnight, the National Disability Insurance Agency (NDIA) has halved travel allowances and abolished jurisdictional loadings. The funding caps – already frozen for five years -have been specifically lowered for physiotherapy, dietitian and podiatry services.

A regional Western Australian physio will lose an untenable $40.06 per hour, with just 18 days’ notice. Providers are understandably incensed. At the time of writing, a Change.org petition has garnered 55,000 signatures. One Far North Queensland practitioner, having already lost money on ‘petrol and wear and tear’, is obliged to travel through ‘wet season floods, high winds and post-cyclone damage’. The halving of the travel allowance will force them to ‘drop three high needs clients’.

Upon inception, the NDIS garnered broad support. The scheme was largely shaped by the Productivity Commission’s 2010-2011 Inquiry. The Commission’s mandate, we should note, is to ‘promote competition and the use of market mechanisms’. As such, since the 2013 NDIS rollout, existing state-based disability services were privatised or disbanded. Recent NDIS news coverage has been largely negative, emphasising waste and fraud. But it is too easy to characterise the providers as greedy.

Price ceilings are used to limit overcharging. At launch, those ceilings were set high enough to encourage provider entry and then largely frozen. Textbook market economics suggest that, over time, a mature competitive market will drive prices down. Competition will find an efficient price, somewhere below the ceiling, as consumers seek the cheapest, highest quality service.

Unfortunately, the NDIS market isn’t behaving like the textbook says it should. Providers are charging at the ceiling rate and participants aren’t finding the cheapest providers. Naughty NDIS. Or is that naughty textbook?

So, why aren’t participants “disciplining the market” and seeking lower prices? When looking for a doctor, one tends to take the first appointment available. And the tendency is to stay with that doctor and trust their advice. These behaviours and trust relationships are prevalent in healthcare. If we expect NDIS participants to drive down prices, we ignore such behavioural realities.

Meanwhile, both NDIS participants and their support coordinators are incentivised to spend their full budget, in case it is reduced in future years. As an independent review into the NDIS acknowledged, ‘there is little reason for providers to compete by lowering the price or improving the quality of supports’ because participants do not routinely change providers, even ‘when prices change’.

Providers do not need to conspire to price-fix at the highest rate. They need only to look at the announced rate and charge at or below the ceiling. Providers naturally charge towards the ceiling rate because this is the strongest anchor in the market and all related costs flow from it. Staff wage expectations are informed by the ceiling rate. Third-party services, such as essential practice management software, are often charged as a percentage of the ceiling rate. And these tendencies inflate real-world provider costs.

To absorb rising costs, in the absence of rising revenue, providers can either eat the loss, degrade the quality of service or minimise staff wages. Once a provider has participants on their books, they want to retain them, due to the substantial onboarding costs for new clients. The NDIS rewards ongoing service rather than specific health outcomes. This encourages institutional overservicing. Regardless, providers who aren’t mindful of their bottom line will not continue to operate.

Some providers may avoid servicing participants with the most complex needs. Such clients may present a “business risk”, with increased service demands and administrative load. Providers can refuse service in favour of the more profitable, less complex clients. As such, it is the most vulnerable who remain underserved by a system that is supposed to achieve the precise opposite.

Critically, it is damaging to perpetually characterise providers as being solely profit-driven. Most healthcare workers enter the service because they wish to provide care. Unless there is proven fraud and abuse, one can reasonably assume that providers are not causing active harm. They form meaningful, professional relationships with their clients. The system is vulnerable to overservicing.

On the other hand, when individual funding is inadequate, many providers risk economic loss and burnout by regularly supplying services pro bono. This practice goes largely unseen by the NDIA.

While the NDIA waits for a mythical market price to emerge, an alternative benchmark is being overlooked: a public provider. Those privatised and disbanded state services, reimagined as the NDIS provider of last resort, could stabilise the market in three important ways.

Firstly, as a backstop for complex presenting clients, whose needs exceed both NDIS funding models and business risk profiles. Secondly, by setting industry minimum conditions for staff and standards for service. Finally, a public provider can be disinflationary, because providers who charge substantially above the public rate, without additional benefit, will fail to attract clients.

The NDIA’s own pricing strategy emphasises that NDIS changes should proceed only with ‘a clear statement to the market’. However, recent pricing announcements appear haphazard, poorly telegraphed and counter to stakeholder input. They create uncertainty for participants and their families. Rate freezes and reductions demoralise providers and risk service closures.

The NDIA wants to drive efficiency. Given the market rationale, this includes some provider closures. But it will not be just the least efficient providers who exit. It will be those providers who depend on higher rates to service remote and complex clients. If they are not careful, the NDIA’s precious market will again fail participants.

Source: https://independentaustralia.net/politics/politics-display/slashing-support-how-the-ndis-is-leaving-the-most-vulner able-behind,19915

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution – Non-Commercial. Appropriate references may be found in the source article.

James Rosier is completing a Master of Economics of Sustainability with Torrens University and is a founding member of Public Money, Public Good.

Leave a Reply